Weitere Beispiele werden automatisch zu den Stichwörtern zugeordnet - wir garantieren ihre Korrektheit nicht.
Firstly, marginal propensity to consume lies between 0 and 1.
"The preliminary evidence suggests that the marginal propensity to consume is about the same this time," he said.
That is, where c is both the average and marginal propensity to consume.
Now let the marginal propensity to consume for the construction company be 'c'.
Second, people with higher incomes have a lower marginal propensity to consume their incomes.
The marginal propensity to consume is higher in a poor country and lower in the case of rich country.
A marginal propensity to consume low enough that high incomes are correlated with people who have already made themselves rich (meritocracy).
Also, marginal propensity to save is opposite of marginal propensity to consume.
To account for these indirect effects of economic activity, economists use economic multipliers that are related to worker's marginal propensity to consume.
Marginal propensity to consume can be found by dividing change in consumption by a change in income, or .
In a capitalist society, with a marginal propensity to consume below one, these are 'automatic' causes of wealth condensation due to variable incomes.
The marginal propensity to consume (MPC) out of each of these accounts is different.
The extent of the multiplier effect is dependent upon the marginal propensity to consume and marginal propensity to import.
For this reason, many empirical studies have attempted to measure the marginal propensity to consume (Barro, 1993, Ch.
Classical economic analysis indicates that the marginal propensity to consume (MPC) decreases as income increases.
If you decide to spend $400 of this marginal increase in income on a new business suit, your marginal propensity to consume will be 0.8 ().
A rich man has a marginal propensity to consume of almost zero, while the propensity to consume of a poor man is almost one.
The marginal propensity to consume (MPC) is the fraction of a change in disposable income that is consumed.
The Keynesian hypothesis is that the marginal propensity to consume is positive but less than unity () is of great analytical and practical significance.
Investment, in its turn, depends upon consumption, and consumption depends upon the marginal propensity to consume (savings rate) across all income categories.
Marginal propensity to consume is present in Keynes' consumption theory and determines by what amount consumption will change in response to a change in income.
The marginal propensity to consume (MPC), on the other hand measures the rate at which consumption is changing when income is changing.
The marginal propensity to consume is measured as the ratio of the change in consumption to the change in income, thus giving us a figure between 0 and 1.
It could not explain the fact that the long-run average propensity to consume seemed to be roughly constant despite the marginal propensity to consume being much lower.
Now again the marginal propensity to consume for these companies is same as the construction company at 'c' and thus, their consumption becomes cx$c i.e. $c.